e-book The Economist - 05 January 2008

Free download. Book file PDF easily for everyone and every device. You can download and read online The Economist - 05 January 2008 file PDF Book only if you are registered here. And also you can download or read online all Book PDF file that related with The Economist - 05 January 2008 book. Happy reading The Economist - 05 January 2008 Bookeveryone. Download file Free Book PDF The Economist - 05 January 2008 at Complete PDF Library. This Book have some digital formats such us :paperbook, ebook, kindle, epub, fb2 and another formats. Here is The CompletePDF Book Library. It's free to register here to get Book file PDF The Economist - 05 January 2008 Pocket Guide.

When choice is demotivating: Can one desire too much of a good thing? Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 79, Jenner, E. Hand hygiene posters: Motivators or mixed messages? Journal of Hospital Infection, 60, Johnson, E. Do defaults save lives?


  • American politics.
  • The Year in Endocrinology 1977.
  • Transparency in Public Policy: Great Britain and the United States;
  • Site Index?
  • Counting the ways.

Science, , Kahneman, D. Thinking, fast and slow. London: Allen Lane. Maps of bounded rationality: Psychology for behavioral economics. The American Economic Review, 93, Representativeness revisited: Attribute substitution in intuitive judgment. Gilovich, D. Kahneman Eds. New York: Cambridge University Press. Evaluation by moments: Past and future. Tversky Eds. Anomalies: The endowment effect, loss aversion, and status quo bias.

Journal of Economic Perspectives , 5 1 , The psychology of preference. Scientific American, , Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk.

An Introduction to Behavioral Economics

Econometrica, 47 , Subjective probability: A judgment of representativeness. Cognitive Psychology, 3, Kardes, F. Consumer inference: a review of processes, bases, and judgment contexts. Journal of Consumer Psychology, 14 3 , Karlsson, N. The ostrich effect: Selective attention to information. Kruger, J. The effort heuristic. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 40 1 , Laibson, D. Golden eggs and hyperbolic discounting. Quarterly Journal of Economics , , Lakshminarayanan, V. The evolution of decision-making under risk: Framing effects in monkey risk preferences. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 47, Levin, I.

All frames are not created equal: A typology and critical analysis of framing effects. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 76, Loewenstein, G. Hot-cold empathy gaps and medical decision-making. Health Psychology, 24 Suppl. Emotions in economic theory and economic behavior. The American Economic Review, 90 2 , Economics behaving badly. The New York Times. Projection bias in predicting future utility. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 4 , Risk as feelings.

Spending other people's money

Psychological Bulletin, 2 , Madrian, B. The power of suggestion: Inertia in k participation and savings behavior. Maheswaran, D. Brand name as a heuristic cue: The effects of task importance and expectancy confirmation on consumer judgments. Journal of Consumer Psychology, 1, March, J. Bounded rationality, ambiguity, and the engineering of choice. The Bell Journal of Economics, 9 2 , Markus, H. Culture and the self: Implications for cognition, emotion and motivation Psychological Review, 98, Mazar, N.

The dishonesty of honest people: A theory of self-concept maintenance. Journal of Marketing Research, 45 6 , Dishonesty in everyday life and its policy implications. Do green products make up better people? Psychological Science, 21, Mazzoni, G. Hindsight bias, the misinformation effect, and false autobiographical memories. Merritt, A. Moral self-licensing: When being good frees us to be bad.

Mitchell, G. Revisiting truth or triviality: The external validity of research in the psychological laboratory. Perspectives on Psychological Science, 7 2 , Moore, D. The trouble with overconfidence. Psychological Review, 2 , Morewedge, C. The least likely of times: How remembering the past biases forecasts of the future. Psychological Science 16 8 , Murphy, S. Affect, cognition, and awareness: Affective priming with optimal and suboptimal stimulus exposures. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 64, Nickerson, R.

Confirmation bias: A ubiquitous phenomenon in many guises. Review of General Psychology, 2, Nisbett, R. Culture and systems of thought: Holistic versus analytic cognition. The Halo Effect: Evidence for unconscious alteration of judgments. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 35, Norton, M. Journal of Consumer Psychology, 22, Doing it now or later. American Economic Review, 89 1 , Odean, T. Volume, volatility, price, and profit when all traders are above average. Journal of Finance, 53 6 , Ofir, C. Memory-based store price judgments: the role of knowledge and shopping experience.

Journal of Retailing, 84 4 , Pallier, G.

London | Economist - World News, Politics, Economics, Business & Finance

The role of individual differences in the accuracy of confidence judgments. Journal of General Psychology, 3 , Prelec, D. The red and the black: Mental accounting of savings and debt. Marketing Science, 17 1 , Always leave home without it: A further investigation of the credit-card effect on willingness to pay.

Marketing Letters.

An inconvenient truth

Read, D. Diversification bias: Explaining the discrepancy in variety seeking between combined and separated choices. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Applied, 1, Rick, S. Tightwads and spendthrifts: An interdisciplinary review. Financial Planning Review, 1 , e Risk-sensitive decision making examined within an evolutionary framework. American Behavioral Scientist, 43 6 , Samson, A. A simple change that could help everyone drink less. Psychology Today. Emergency purchasing situations: Implications for consumer decision-making.

Journal of Economic Psychology, 44, Two minds, three ways: Dual system and process models in consumer psychology. Academy of Marketing Science Review, 2, 48— Samuelson, W. Status quo bias in decision making. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 1, Schwartz, B. The paradox of choice: Why more is less.

New York: Ecco. Shah, A. Heuristics made easy: an effort-reduction framework. Shampanier, K. Zero as a special price: The true value of free products. Marketing Science, 26, Shang, J. Field experiments in charitable contribution: The impact of social influence on the voluntary provision of public goods. The Economic Journal , , — Shepperd, J. Exploring the causes of comparative optimism.

Psychologica Belgica, 42, Shiller, R. Irrational exuberance. Shiv, B. Placebo effects of marketing actions: Consumers may get what they pay for. Journal of Marketing Research, 42 4 , Simon, H. Models of bounded rationality. Slovic, P. The affect heuristic. Violence risk assessment and risk communication: The effects of using actual cases, providing instructions, and employing probability vs.

Law and Human Behavior, 24 3 , Strecher, V. Goal setting as a strategy for health behavior change. Health Education Quarterly , 22, Sullivan, P. Thaler, R. Misbehaving: The making of behavioral economics. Allen Lane. Mental accounting and consumer choice. Marketing Science , 27, Mental accounting matters. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making. Anomalies: Saving, fungibility, and mental accounts.

The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 4, Nudge: Improving decisions about health, wealth, and happiness. Save More Tomorrow: Using behavioral economics to increase employee saving. Journal of Political Economy, , SS Gambling with the house money and trying to break even: The effects of prior outcomes on risky choice. Management Science, 36 6 , Thorndike, A. A 2-phase labeling and choice architecture intervention to improve healthy food and beverage choices. American Journal of Public Health, 3 , Triandis, H.

Interpersonal behavior. Tulving, E. Priming effects in word fragment completion are independent of recognition memory. Tversky, A. The Framing of Decisions and the Psychology of Choice. Science , , Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases. Science New Series , , Vohs, K. Wansink, B. An anchoring and adjustment model of purchase quantity decisions. Journal of Marketing Research, 35 1 , 71— Wilson, T. Affective forecasting. Advances in Experimental Social Psychology, 35, Cobh's supermarket, fast-food restaurants and other shops are flourishing too.

Quantifying the impact of all this is tricky. A report by PricewaterhouseCoopers concluded that a surge in migration has helped to lift Britain's growth rate above its long-term trend.

Michael Porter

Alexandros Zavos, of the Hellenic Migration Policy Institute in Athens, reckons that immigration into Greece has recently added as much as 1. For countries that have long had high rates of immigration, such as America, sustained economic growth partly reflects an ever-growing workforce. Sceptics say that migration may boost the economy as a whole, but on a per-head basis the benefits for the natives are less impressive.

Migrationwatch, an anti-migration group in Britain, reckons that for the average Briton the inflow of foreigners provides just a few extra pence a week. Roy Beck, an anti-immigrant activist in America, suggests that countries with ageing workforces should try to make their economies less labour-dependent. But some jobs such as cleaning or nursing cannot be sent abroad or mechanised. And even if more natives can be trained to do highly skilled work, shrinking native workforces in many countries could mean economic contraction. Some of the sceptics' arguments touch raw political nerves, particularly when it comes to the least well-off natives in the host country.

In America the share of national income that is going to the poorest has been shrinking in recent decades. Inequality has increased and the real wages of the least skilled have fallen. Circumstantial evidence suggests that foreigners, who typically work in less skilled jobs, might be partly to blame. If the illegal workers could be counted, the figures would probably be much higher still.

Do migrants make life worse for poor natives? Studies comparing wages in American cities with and without lots of foreigners suggest that they make little difference to the income of the poorest. But Mr Borjas also calculated how a rise in the number of migrants might have encouraged the creation of jobs, which reduced the impact on wages. This tallies with the outcome of natural experiments in recent history, such as the influx of , Russian Jews into Israel in the early s, the return of , Frenchmen from Algeria in or the homecoming of , Portuguese after the collapse of their empire in Africa in Each time the influx of workers expanded the workforce and wages dropped slightly, but subsequently recovered.

Given prolonged immigration, argues Steven Camorata of the Centre for Immigration Studies, the impact is sustained. Worse, say the sceptics, migration may limit poor natives' chances of moving up to better-paid jobs.

Now for the tweaks

With changing economies that reward skills, it is anyway getting harder to move up the ladder from low-wage jobs to better-paid ones. Now migrants, especially those with skills and drive, are making life even harder for the weakest natives. A second worry is that migrants will put a strain on public services and the tax system. It is in schools, public housing and doctors' surgeries that natives come face to face with migrants and it is often at the local and state level, where responsibility for such services usually lies, that hostility to migrants seems strongest.

Local councils in Britain complain that clinics and schools are overloaded and central government is slow to dish out help, and local police in areas with many immigrants blame foreigners for a rise in crime. In Greece, as new illegal immigrants arrive at remote spots on the border, officials complain that they lack funds for policing and social services. Several states have passed tough new laws banning illegal migrants from using their public services. But crowding, although likely to cause resentment, results from the unexpected arrival of those migrants, with bureaucracies taking time to allocate resources to the right places.

In itself, it does not prove that migrants are a drag on public services as a whole. Indeed, migrants often make a large contribution to the public purse. When a foreign worker first arrives, usually as a young adult, fully educated and in good health, he makes few demands on schools or clinics.

Joseph Stiglitz - Will the Economic Stimulus Package Work?

A legal immigrant will pay taxes just like any native; even an illegal one will contribute something if only through the tax on those bottles of bison grass vodka. On the other hand, voters in many rich countries seem increasingly hostile to immigration, which suggests that politicians may find it more and more difficult to allow immigration to continue at its current high level.

If only there were some means of getting all the benefits of migration but none of the costs. That is the thinking behind the latest solution now being promoted: circular migration. Europe's commissioner for justice and home affairs, Franco Frattini, wants to see more temporary migrants in the EU. For the highly skilled, he suggests a blue card similar to America's green one to ease the temporary entry of professionals and their families into Europe.

Foreign workers with the most skills make up just 1. A blue card would at least make it clear to migrant professionals that they would be welcome. On the other hand, highly skilled workers go in search of dynamic economies, along with the high pay and bright careers they offer, and a blue card would do nothing to bring more dynamism to Europe. What of the less skilled? Mr Frattini points to a pilot project in Spain over the past two years in which Moroccans—especially women—have been brought in to do specific jobs on farms and in hotels for a few months at a time and then sent home again.

Contracts are drawn up beforehand, travel is part-funded by the EU , everything is above board, and so far every migrant has gone back as agreed. As a result, 10, Moroccan workers did not have to run the risk of taking a patera across the Strait of Gibraltar. They were able to send remittances home but put no strain on Spain's public services. Mr Frattini wants to launch another pilot programme in his native Italy, where southern farmers might recruit workers from Egypt or Tunisia.

Moldova and Ukraine want to get involved in similar schemes. If the projects work one in Corsica was less successful , Mr Frattini would like to scale them up, with member countries eventually setting import quotas for foreign labour. The EU is planning to establish job centres in north Africa, beginning with one in Mali, to offer a legal route to jobs in Europe, and also provide some language training.

But this part of what Mr Frattini and others call circular migration has been tried before and seems unlikely to bring the hoped-for benefits. Germany's Gastarbeiter scheme began in , drawing workers first from southern Europe and north Africa and then Turkey. Something similar was done in France and the Netherlands, mostly with workers from north Africa.

America imported Mexican farm labourers under its Bracero programme. The trouble is that such a dirigiste design is not well suited to today's liberal democracies and their flexible labour markets. And unless schemes are tightly regulated and the exit of workers is enforced by law, everybody has an interest in keeping the supposedly termporary workers in place. Employers would much prefer not to have to train new people every six months, and workers want to keep their jobs or move on to better ones.

Many of the guest workers who arrived in northern Europe from Turkey and north Africa in the s and s never left, and eventually brought their families to live with them too. The old joke that there is nothing so permanent as a temporary migrant has more than a grain of truth in it. It might be possible to create financial incentives for migrants to leave at the end of their contract period. Co-operation between the governments of the host and the sending countries would be essential, says Mr Frattini. And migrants could be policed more tightly with the aid of new technology: ID cards, databases with biometric details, systems like E -verify in America that allow employers to check whether workers are authorised to be in the country.

Proponents of circular migration admit that it would entail a loss of privacy. The biggest problem, though, is that people who expect to be packed off home after six months will be seen as second-class residents, and will have less incentive to integrate with their hosts. Why learn the language or adopt local habits and values for just a few months?